THE unquestioned
success which Poulett Thomson had scored in the House of Commons had
already completely reconciled his friends to his new sphere of activity,
despite the heavy expense of frequent elections during these unsettled
years.
During 1830 several
important events occurred. George VI died and was succeeded by William
IV, necessitating a new election. Huskisson having met with untimely
death, the suggestion was made that Poulett Thomson should be chosen to
succeed him in the representation of Liverpool; but a strong local
candidate coming forward, the idea was dropped. Finally, in November,
1830. the Duke of Wellington's government resigned and Earl Grey came in
at the head of the first administration pledged to reform, though some
of its members were not very ardent in that cause,, Viscount Althorp was
the new Chancellor of the Exchequer, and his high appreciation of
Poulett Thomson's abilities led to his being offered the position of
vice-president of the Board of Trade and treasurer of the navy.
With the death of
Huskisson the public seemed to turn to Poulett Thomson as the natural
successor of that distinguished advocate of large views and Liberal
principles, and as the fitting representative of the rising commercial
and industrial interests of the country. Moreover, Poulett Thomson, in
addition to his wide grasp of economic conditions and needs, was much
more tactful and discreet than Mr. Huskisson had been in dealing with
the public, and especially with opponents. The president and nominal
head of the Board of Trade in this ministry was Lord Auckland, who was,
however, a very reticent and colourless minister, commonly understood to
have been added to the cabinet more for ornament than use, it being
necessary to have a few peers in the ministry of reform to give it an
air of respectability. Poulett Thomson, therefore, was virtually head of
the department, and represented it in the House of Commons. He became
actual president of the Board in 1834.
Mr. Thomson's
appointment made it necessary for him to withdraw from active
participation in business, hence the partnership with his brother was
dissolved. As he was re-elected without opposition, he immediately
applied himself with characteristic energy to his new duties, seeking to
realize in office what he had advocated in opposition. In practice
almost every reform, from the very nature of the case, involves the
sacrifice of some vested interest or pre-established claims. Thus, for
instance, when during the war foreign allies were irregular in their
supply, heavy duties had been imposed in order to foster the kelp
fisheries on the north east of Scotland from which a weak alkali was
obtained. When, subsequently, trade had resumed its normal channel, the
British soap industry found itself heavily handicapped by excessive
duties on such articles as barilla, a crude soda-carbonate commonly
brought from Spain or the Levant. When, as one of his first reforms,
Thomson had secured a reduction of the duty on barilla, the Scottish
landlords resented the fiscal change as fiercely as their English
brethren did the suggestion of a reduction of the duty on corn. Such
were the difficulties which the new president of the Board of Trade met
with at every turn in his efforts to simplify and reform the complicated
British fiscal system.
It was generally
supposed, from the nature of the r relations, that Lord Althorp's first
budget, brought down on February 11th, 1831, contained a good many
features which originated with the new vice-president of the Board of
Trade. At any rate he obtained full credit for every interference with
vested interests which it contained, and received due castigation from
the disappointed monopolists. The proposed reduction 011 the timber
duties was thrown out on a combination of certain ship-owners and
colonial investors with the Opposition and with a considerable element
in the ministerial ranks, who felt that >f this were permitted to pass
their turn might come next. Yet, when the Opposition came into power in
1841, their first budget contained a similar proposal, but though it
shared the same fate it aided in preparing the way for the ultimate
abolition of this very onerous preference granted by the Mother Country
to the American colonies, and which in reality produced no corresponding
advantage to the colonies, for it simply promoted the reckless and
wasteful destruction of Canadian forests.
Poulett Thomson was now
so completely absorbed in the intricate details pertaining to the
financial and fiscal aspects of his office, that he took but little part
in the great debates of 1831-2 on the Reform Bill. In this, however, as
we have said, he was deeply interested, and two of his most intimate
friends, Lord IAlthorp and Lord Durham, had a chief part in the framing
of the bill.
He devoted special
attention at this time to a commission appointed for the revision of the
system of keeping the public accounts; of this Sir Henry Parnell was
chairman, and his friend Dr. Bowring, the noted authority on financial
matters, was secretary. As the result of their labours, the accounting
of the British public offices was brought into harmony with the most
approved methods of modern business. We shall find Lord Sydenham
directing a similar and much needed revision in Canada.
In November, 1831, Mr.
Poulett Thomson and Lord Durham went to Pans to follow up the previous
informal discussions and to set on foot negotiations for a new
commercial treaty with France. The joint commission named by the two
governments consisted of Mr. George Villiers, afterwards Earl of
Clarendon, and l)r. Bowring, representing England, and Messieurs
Freville and Duchatel, representing France. The instructions for the
British commissioners were drawn up by Poulett Thomson. There was not
much difficulty, 011 the part of the commissioners, in arriving at a
provisional agreement based 011 sound principles of international trade,
but it was quite another matter to secure any actual alterations in the
existing tariffs which might affect disadvantageously those interests
which were at the time reaping profits at the public expense. The work
of the commission continued at intervals until 1835, and though at the
time only very limited concessions were secured, the way was prepared
for much greater results later on.
In the course of his
work at the Board of Trade, Poulett Thomson still found that on every
hand he had to contend with special interests, domestic and colonial,
which either stoutly resisted all attempts at reform, or, under
reactionary influences, sought to restore anomalies which had been
removed either Mr. Huskisson's time or his own. In 1832, notwithstanding
objections to all innovations in the tariff, he introduced and piloted
through parliament an important measure effecting an extensive
consolidation of the excise duties. The energy with which he threw
himself into such work, involving as it did an immense amount of detail,
naturally told upon his constitution. An item from his journal will
indicate how great the strain was. August 28th, Saturday.—"A week of the
hardest possible labour. I have not returned from the House' any day
till three o'clock; on Wednesday not till four. It is impossible to
stand this! I find my body quite exhausted, and my mind equally worn
out. All this week I have alternated between the Bank and Silk
Committees, and then the House. On Wednesday I carried my Bill (the
Customs Duties) through the Committee: was at it from five till two in
the morning, nine mortal hours!.....I passed my Bill to-day, thank God!"
At the close of the
session he made a tour through the manufacturing districts of the north
of England and southwest of Scotland, acquiring a practical acquaintance
with the typical industries of the country and the shipping centres of
Glasgow and Liverpool.
The principles which he
upheld in the House of ("ominous were so thoroughly appreciated by the
electors of Manchester that he had been urged to offer himself as a
candidate for that borough when first erected into an independent
constituency as the result of the Reform Act. Though highly flattered by
the proposals of his Manchester friends,
he doubted the wisdom
of attempting to change his constituency. Hence, while expressing his
high appreciation of the honour of representing such a borough, he
declined to undertake the campaign, and once more declared himself a
candidate for Dover. Even oil such terms his Manchester friends
continued to prosecute their canvass; the result was, that while he was
elected at the head of the poll in Dover, he was also returned by a
large majority as one of the members for Manchester. As this expression
of esteem and confidence came to him chiefly in virtue of his political
principles and parliamentary services from a constituency representing
one of the most enlightened and enterprising sections of England, he
naturally esteemed it a signal honour. It was the more gratifying in
that, owing to the peculiar composition of the House of Commons and the
unsatisfactory state of parties, conscientious attention to the public
interest and the details of office were but indifferently appreciated m
most parts of the country outside a limited circle of enthusiasts.
Though loath to break the ties which had been formed with many
supporters in Dover, he could not but decide to accept Manchester. Its
great importance as the chief manufacturing centre in Britain gave him
just that added influence and weight n the House and in the cabinet
which was needed to support the commercial and fiscal reforms for which
he stood.
The borough of
Manchester prepared to celebrate in fitting manner <ts new liberties and
it$ new members. The speech of Mr. Poulett Thomson was worthy of the
occasion. Undoubtedly the most vital issue before the country as a whole
was the question as to how far the tide of reform which had been
steadily rising for some years past was to be allowed to flow. Staunch
Tories had consistently opposed it from the first, the more conservative
Whigs, forming the chief body of the ministry under whose administration
the Reform Act had been carried, had already said, "So far, but no
farther," giving expression to their convictions in the famous
"finality" dictum. On the other hand, the more doctrinaire Radicals, a
steadily increasing element but with no very definite boundaries, saw
opening before them an indefinite programme of democratic reforms,
several of which appeared quite revolutionary to the more cautious
statesmen of that day. It was the alarming programme of more reforms to
follow which was chiefly responsible for the application of the
"finality' brake by the Whigs who had passed the Reform Act.
It was this question of
future reforms which the new member for Manchester frankly faced before
his new costituency, which now heard him for the first time. He declined
to accept either the Conservative or the Radical solution, but
maintained that the correct policy was that of the open mind to sound
ideas, and the open door for reasonable progress. But this, he held,
implied ft careful testing, by reference to the actual needs of the
time, of every step in the series of progressive measures. Taking up in
detail the questions of his own department, he proceeded to give
concrete illustrations of urgent reforms which were yet to be
undertaken. In the forefront he naturally placed the need for a more
liberal commercial policy. Referring to the opposition which his efforts
had hitherto met with, he says, "I have been for years exposed to all
the shafts which malice or ignorance could point against me for the
devotion which I have ever shown to these principles." And what were
these principles? "They are the most perfect freedom of exchange —a fair
field for our industries —and no restrictions, beyond what for fiscal
purposes are necessary, upon the exertions of our manufacturers." He
then outlined in concrete shape the whole argument which was years
afterwards to free the trade of Britain from its trammels, and enable
her to lead the world for another half century. The following extract
from his speech will quite fully indicate the principles which he
advocated, and the manner in which he presented them.
"But, say the advocates
of this admirable recipe for getting rich by Act of Parliament,
protection is necessary to secure our industry from foreign competition.
What are the effects it has produced in this respect in this country?
You see it illustrated at home in a manner which cannot fail to have
been present to every man's mind long ere this. Let me ask you what
protection has been given to that great manufacture which gives
employment to hundreds of thousands—nay, to miliums I may say —within
the great district which encircles your city? What protection has the
cotton trade had? I answer, none whatever! Unaided by any legislative
enactment—unassisted by the fostering hand of power—unprotected by the
custom-house book —this great manufacture has grown from an infant's
condition until it has attained a giant's strength. We see it with one
arm encircle the conquests of the New World, and with another shower its
productions into the very heart of that country, the vast empire of
India, which was formerly its successful rival, and extending and
pushing forth the fruits of its industry even into the central regions
of Africa, where no European foot was ever yet stamped. This, gentlemen,
is the success which has attended a manufacture which was not the pet of
the legislature. Let me now mark the course of another manufacture
fenced round by protections of all kinds, equally a production of a
foreign country—the raw material equally brought from a distance—arid
thus affording a fit comparison with that which I have named. What was
the case with silk? Was protection wanting there? Were there no laws
which restricted foreign competition—were there no penalties upon those
who attempted to introduce it? And did all this protection, amounting to
absolute and total prohibition, tend to make this branch of industry
flourish and extend itself? Under the auspices of the coast blockade and
the search warrant did it realize the theories of the protectionists?
Was it found that that manufacture, irivalling and outstripping all its
competitors in foreign countries, obtained an extension like its poorer
and unprotected, but therefore more hardy, brother? No such tiling—not
only did it not attain the vigour which would enable it to reach foreign
climes, but, in spite of your prohibitory laws—in spite of your
penalties exacted from the unfortunate smuggler, it was met even in this
country at every turn by its foreign competitors. In these two branches
then, we may read the history of the fallacy of protection. My system,
then, is this: Leave to industry a full and fair field—relieve us from
your unwise protection— remove from us your well-meant but injudicious
care—leave us alone, let our talent, our capital and our invention
follow their free course, and what I see before me to-day removes, if I
ever had, any doubt that we shall then have 110 rivals to fear, no
competitors to dread. . . .
"I contend, and I have
contended, that if we consent to take from foreign countries that which
they produce, they must of necessity receive from us in payment our
productions. They may raise up libraries of custom-house books—they may
surround their territories with custom-house officers—they may fill
their seas with cruisers—but, if we are to take anything from them, they
must take from us in return. The principle, then, which I have
advocated, is to follow out, straightforwardly, our own course, to
remove the unnecessary restrictions and prohibitions from the
productions of other countries, and to trust to one of two consequences
resulting; either a sense of their own folly, winch will induce them to
adopt a better system of legislation, or to that necessity which 1
contend must exist—if they wish to take advantage of us—that they should
admit, somehow or other, what we can give them ill payment."
This will indicate how
completely Poulett Thomson had worked out for himself the free trade
policy which has long been familiar to England, but which at that time
was regarded with so much patriotic apprehension by many ill-informed
yet able and conscientious men, and with so much aversion by others who
were actuated only by a narrow and persona] selfishness. In Manchester,
however, these ideas were better understood and more intelligently
appreciated, and, as their member was free to confess, "the confidence
which you, the electors of this great metropolis of the manufacturing
industry of the world, have reposed in me, unsought and unsolicited,—an
honour which I never hoped to obtain, and which I should never have
sought to achieve, —is indeed the most convincing and irresistible
answer to attacks of that description."
The strenuous nature of
the welcome which his new constituents extended to him may be inferred
from the following entry in his journal.
Sunday night, December
30th, 1832.—"Tins has been a week of prodigious excitement, and I have
had no time to set down one word. Monday at the Exchange. Tuesday,
Christmas Day, quiet. Thursday, the dinner, the proudest day of my life,
1,250 people sat down, Hey wood m the chair. I spoke an hour and a half,
and, I think, well. Friday dined at Heywood's, and Saturday night left
for town, very ill. To-day sent for Copeland."
It may be inferred that
after the election of 1832 Poulett Thomson did not relax his efforts in
the House of Commons or in the cabinet towards promoting tariff reform.
While eloquently advocating the larger features of tariff reform such as
the reduction and final abolition of the Corn Laws, the relief of sugar,
timber, wool and cotton, which required, however, for their ultimate
acceptance a long course of education, he went on with the work of
classifying and simplifying the duties, relieving where possible the
burdens on minor articles which while contributing little to the revenue
distressed both manufacturer and consumer by the exorbitant rates which
were levied. These reforms were managed with a quiet, tact which escaped
the notice at once of his organized opponents and of the public at
large. Thus, under cover of the general educational campaign for freedom
of trade on a large scale, between 1832 and 1830, the president of the
Board of Trade had secured reductions of duty, some of them of very
considerable percentages, on three hundred and seventy-two articles, and
had greatly simplified the duties on many others. I he same system and
the same principles were followed by Sir Robert Peel and. Mr. Gladstone
in preparing for their larger measures at a later date.
A subject to which he
naturally gave special attention, and on which his experience was to be
called into requisition in Canada, was that of banking. On this subject
he held very definite views, the views afterwards embodied by S>r Robert
Peel n the Bank Act of 184-4, which introduced the system still
regulating banking in Britain. The essent'al feature of the system, as
regards the issue of paper money, is that the paper currency of the
country should be issued by a single national bank, solely against
bullion, and would therefore fluctuate with the amount of bullion in the
country. A certain permanent nucleus of the reserve might be held in
government securities, which would not, however, affect the large margin
of bullion, upon the ebb and flow of which the note issue of the country
would depend. For a country situated as England, at the centre of the
world's financial and exchange business, such a system has proved on the
whole very satisfactory. The practical experience and economic arguments
with which Poulett Thomson supported his views, which were shared by the
best financiers of the tune, were amply justified in subsequent British
history. As to whether such a system was quite as fully applicable to
the condition of a colony such as Canada in 1811, we shall have to
consider later.
To Poulett Thomson's
lot also fell the duty of superintending the passing of the Act for
regulating the labour of children in factories, and its subsequent
administration by the commission appointed to carry it out. At the close
of the session of 1833, he sought a rest in a tour of the Rhine, and
spent the month of October at Paris endeavouring to forward the
negotiations for a commercial treaty.
During the following
session of 1834, the Corn Law question was again much in evidence. The
able and indefatigable member for Middlesex, Mr. Joseph Hume, brought on
his long-expected motion on the subject. Not content with the
sliding-scale system of duties adopted in 1828, he urged a still further
reduction to a moderate fixed duty. Mr. Poulett Thomson naturally came
to the aid of the free trade forces, and on the 7th of March delivered
one of his most important speeches m parliament. As yet those opposed to
the Corn Laws were decidedly in the minority in the House of Commons,
even on the side of the Whig party.
Hence, in supporting
Mr. Hume's motion, Poulett Thomson as a member of the government, though
not yet in the cabinet, was in opposition to the majority of his
colleagues, an opposition which was most pronounced in the case of Sir
James Graham, First Lord of the Admiralty, to whose arguments in support
of the sliding scale he devoted some strong, though respectful,
criticism. The fact was that Sir James Graham had not been for some time
oil the best of terms with the majority of the cabinet, though one of
the most advanced advocates of the Reform Act, and indeed a member of
the small committee which drafted it. Though not in sympathy with the
more extreme form of the Corn Laws, he was not as yet prepared to accept
any serious lowering of the duties on grain. Yet he wras destined some
twelve years later to be Peel's most advanced supporter in securing the
complete abolition of the Corn Laws. At present his chief difficulty
with his Whig colleagues was over the question of the Irish Church, he
being an uncompromising supporter of the Establishment. This friction in
the cabinet foreshadowed the readjustment which was soon to take place,
and which was to relieve it. of its most Conservative element.
In the main body of his
speech in support of Mr. Hume's motion, Poulett Thomson passed in review
the actual history of the Corn Laws from the beginning of the existing
system in 1815, pointing out that it had been a burden upon the public
while ail unsteady and delusive favour to the farmer. He maintained that
the strength of Britain lay in her manufacturing industries, which
should be encouraged by the double process of fostering trade with other
countries by purchasing their produce, which in turn would encourage the
purchase of British wares instead of forcing foreigners to prematurely
attempt manufacturing for themselves because they could find no market
for their own produce. This was indeed the situation which became so
effective some years later in the United States as the justification for
building up a protective system there. As usual he did not argue his
case upon merely abstract principles assumed to be applicable to all
countries in the world. He dealt with the actual condition of Britain
itself, which, however, he treated in no narrow manner, but in a broad
and comprehensive spirit. There were, it is true, many ardent
free-traders who insisted upon generalizing the British conditions in
such fashion as to conclude that the trade policy which was most
suitable for Britain must be equally suitable for all other countries,
and that therefore the adoption of free trade in Britain might be
expected to be followed by its adoption m all other countries. Though
Poulett Thomson hoped to see the trade of the world much freer than it
then was, he nevertheless regarded as the best for Britain the freedom
of trade which he advocated, whatever policy other countries might
adopt. It s one of the circumstances most flattering to the fulness and
accuracy of his knowledge and the soundness of the judgments which he
founded upon it, that nearly all of the practical principles which he
maintained, and the features of political policy which he advocated,
have been fully realized in the course of British development. Yet, in
advocating most of the features of his trade policy and financial
reforms, he was considerably in advance of his colleagues, and, as we
have seen, frequently in opposition to them, where the question was
permitted, as in the case of the Corn Laws, to be treated as an open
one. But though thus closely in line with so many great features of
policy which were ultimately to prevail, his early death prevented his
seeing any of them finally accepted. |